AmbienteDiritto.it - Rivista giuridica - Electronic Law Review - Copyright © AmbienteDiritto.it
Testata registrata presso il Tribunale di Patti Reg. n. 197 del 19/07/2006
Oil and the Bad News Principle
Ferdinand E. Banks*
Abstract
According to Matthew Simmons, a
former energy adviser to President Bush, “Too many people are looking at OPEC
through the rear-view mirror. There is a resolve in OPEC’s eyes to never to go
back to the days of cheap oil.” Not only in their eyes but in their actions –
that is to say in their investment policies – which have resulted in (the
unspoken) intention to refrain from bringing too much additional oil to market.
The director of the important consultancy PRC Energy, Robin West, has
brilliantly summed up the present oil situation by saying that “the full impact
of the nationalisations that took place in the l960s and l970s are taking place
now”. They are taking place now and those of us on the buy side of the market
can only “take it and like it”, to use the terminology of Humphrey Bogart.
Key words: Peak oil, real versus nominal oil prices, futures markets
Let’s start this short paper by getting the peak oil issue off the table.
Peak oil is not about the future – it’s about the past!. It’s about a (generally
unspoken) strategy formulated many years ago by the most important countries in
OPEC, which features a decrease in the production of their invaluable oil (and
probably also gas) when they get the opportunity. The present high oil price
has given them the opportunity!. It’s about more money rather than less –
that is to say run-of-the-mill Economics 101 profit maximization – and for
students of financial economics, increasing the value of an option whose
underlying is the asset called oil, by extending the exercise date (i.e. the
date on which that oil will be harvested). As might be shown by serious teachers
with a serious interest in the so-called dismal science, it’s about controlling
certain elements of the global oil supply curve, which is equivalent to
controlling the entire curve. Basically, it’s not about geology but about
microeconomics, and as a result the oil price reaching a level that even I
thought was impossible. It’s also about macroeconomics.
Perhaps another jolt to the delicate sensibilities of readers might be
appropriate at the present time. Neither the OPEC countries nor ‘Big Oil’ have
the ability nor intentions of producing the EXTRA tens of millions of barrels of
oil that will be necessary to make the half-baked dreams of the International
Energy Agency (IEA) and the United States Department of Energy (USDOE) come true,
by which I mean the extra tens of millions of barrels that will be required to
fill the global demand-supply ‘gap’ in their target year of 2030. And if the
major producers do not gradually work their way up to that level, then it will
never be realized, and the oil price will continue to ascend unless ‘demand is
destroyed’ by an international macroeconomic meltdown. Readers can ponder what
this means at their leisure, however the information provided in an important
paper of James D. Hamilton (2008) does not leave much room for optimism.
The Oil Price and Macroeconomics
Several years ago, in a discussion in the Journal of Economic Perspectives
(Fall, 2006), it was claimed that “disturbances in the oil market are likely to
matter less for the U.S. macroeconomic performance than has commonly been
thought”. Exactly what this was all about is difficult to say, because
macroeconomic downturns which featured real growth falling and inflation rising
(i.e. stagflation) immediately followed the oil price increases of 1973, 1980,
1981, and 1990, although a cheerful note was that in the macroeconomic sense
recovery took a comparatively short time. There were of course individuals and
firms for whom recovery never really arrived, and needless to say recessionary
tendencies in the U.S. impacted on the rest of the world to one extent or
another, but as to be expected, there were more than a few academic and business
economists who claimed that the correlation between oil price rises and
macroeconomic downturns had finally been broken.
It would certainly be wonderful if this were the case, because the manner in
which the oil price is presently increasing is not reassuring at all according
to the economics and finance that I teach. The previous oil price rises were ‘spikes’,
but even so economic growth declined in several regions. By way of contrast, at
the present time we are facing a sustained price rise, and the possible
development of a situation that in some respects contains elements of the
scare-scenario posited by the leading investment bank in the U.S. – Goldman
Sachs – in its Global Economics Weekly of April 10, 2002.
Two academics who have elected to evaluate the oil price-macroeconomic
interconnection mentioned above, and who were (and perhaps still are) not
worried about any damage that could be inflicted on the U.S. (and global)
economy by high oil prices, are Robert B. Barsky and Lutz Kilian (2004). In one
of those many unread journals gathering dust in our academic libraries, they
told us that “disturbances in the oil market are likely to matter less for U.S.
performance than had commonly been thought”.
Noting that this conclusion follows an econometric analysis – where emphasis
should be put on the syllable ‘con’ – I reminded myself once again that despite
some lopsided opinions to the contrary, empirical work in economics can never
take the place of theory. But even so, of the thousands of papers that in one
form or another originate every year in academia, this is one of the few that
makes a systematic attempt to judge the impact of oil price movements on the
macroeconomic price level, employment, productivity and economic growth. I am
also generous enough to believe that the reason those two authors concluded that
in general the effect of oil price increases tends to be exaggerated, is because
over the period of their investigations (1970-2003), with the exception of the
first and possibly the second oil price shocks, they were dealing with narrow
‘spikes’ instead of sustained escalations. Of course, a spike from the present
oil price (which touched $138.54/b on June 6) could be devastating for many
persons in every part of the world, since changes in the oil price – and
particularly upward movements – influences all energy prices.
And when I say “all” energy prices, I do not mean just natural gas. I also mean
coal, and that is not something to look forward to, given the amount of coal
that is and will continue to be consumed.
There is “no support for the notion that increased uncertainty leads to a sharp
fall in investment that in turn contributes to a recession”, the two authors
tell us. What they mean by that is no econometric evidence, although it might be
suggested that intelligent readers of the business press would be wise not
attach any merit to a remark of this nature in the near and possibly distant
future. Thus I suggest that we amend their observation to read ‘increased
uncertainty can lead to a sharp fall in investment that – if sufficiently sharp
– can lead to or deepen a recession, and possible help to generate a depression’.
The economics here is really very simple, and receives an extensive review in my
energy economics textbooks (2000, 2007). Uncertainty functions in such a way as
to boost discount factors, which as we all know from Economics 102 has a
negative effect on physical investment because it means a large reduction in the
(expected) present value of distant revenues. It is no more than common sense
that investors who could accept a certain (or nearly certain) return of 8%,
desire e.g. 11% when confronted with uncertainty because they feel that
something might go drastically wrong.
Barsky and Kilian take a cavalier view about physical investment, citing among
other things their disbelief in Professor Ben Bernanke’s ‘bad news principle’,
which the future Federal Reserve boss applied to oil price shocks (1983). What
this comes down to is firms postponing investment “as they attempt to find out
whether the increase in the price of oil is transitory or permanent”.
Although Barsky and Kilian say that evidence exists that Bernanke’s “waiting”
effect is small relative to the magnitudes that need to be explained, I doubt
whether this contention deserves to be treated with excessive respect when the
oil price reaches its present level. For what it is worth – which isn’t much any
longer – the real (inflation adjusted) price of oil (as compared to the money or
nominal price) has been constant or falling for the last 30 years, and until
recently the great majority of energy professionals interested in oil have
preached from every soapbox between the Bay of Fundy and the Capetown Navy Yard
that real prices of oil would continue to decline. As a result many firms were
quick to take advantage of what they judged to be decent investment
opportunities. In the light of both nominal and real oil price increases over
the past two years, however, many or most of these firms are going to be much
more careful, which will tend to give extra weight to expected bad news about
energy prices.
Incidentally, Bernanke actually said that “of possible future outcomes, only the
unfavourable ones have a bearing on the current propensity to undertake a given
project”. This kind of thinking ties in with a key postulate of real options
theory: when waiting is possible, downside risk is always the major factor.
The Oil Price and the Wisdom of Bill O’Reilly
I hope to wake up some beautiful morning and find that everybody believes in the
peak oil theory, even if it turns out to be false. Of course, the boss of the
European Union’s Energy Directorate once called it a theory that is no different
from any other, but in truth it is somewhat different from the dozens or perhaps
hundreds that he encounters every day in the corridors and restaurants of the EU
office building in Brussels, most of which have to do with pay increases, the
renewals of contracts, and various travel oriented welfare schemes. If
governments do not believe in this (peak oil) theory, then they may fail to do
what has to be done to keep an energy catastrophe at bay, where such a
catastrophe can be generated merely by demand outrunning supply for a long time,
without supply actually turning down. Incidentally, this is an application of
(Albert) Einstein’s equivalence principle.
Perhaps the most provocative information offered on this topic recently
originated with the Cambridge Energy Research Associates (CERA), whose director
– Daniel Yergin – is a winner of the Pulitzer Prize (for a book about oil titled
‘The Prize’). Apparently CERA doesn’t believe in a global peaking of the oil
production, but instead claims to have theoretical and/or statistical proof that
we will eventually experience an undulating plateau. (Let me note though that as
a veteran teacher of game theory, I recognize the likelihood that in reality
they may believe in a distinct peaking of the world oil production even more
than I do, but for reasons of a monetary nature find it expedient to devise a
cock-and-bull story about an undulating peak.)
Another person who has forwarded an offbeat hypothesis about the oil price is Mr
Bill O’Reilly, who is an important political and social commentator in the
United States. Let me make it clear however that he is considerably less than
important to me, even if I agree with a few things that he says.
To O’Reilly’s way of thinking, a large portion of the increase in the oil price
is due to the machinations of speculators in – according to him – Las Vegas. I
think that we would all be better off if we completely ignored that gentleman’s
opinions and pronouncements on this subject, to include his famous statement
“supply and demand my carburator”. It very definitely is supply and demand that
explains all except a few dollars of the oil price, Bill, regardless of your
opinions and the opinions of certain researchers in some of the largest
financial institutions in the world.
What Mr O’Reilly was alluding to are the activities of hedge funds, which are
also mentioned quite often in the financial press. I once knew quite a bit about
hedge funds, but lost interest in them after being given a boring lecture on the
beauty of those assets by a hedge fund hustler just before I departed for a
visiting professorship in Hong Kong. The truth of hedge funds is similar to the
truth of operations like the Nordic Electricity Exchange (NORDPOOL), whose
strength is in the laziness of their clients. There are approximately 8500 hedge
funds in the world, and every year about 1000 either go out of business or are
close to shutting their doors, but even so they are treated with a respect that
bears no correlation to their performance.
Before concluding I note that Professor Martin Feldstein (of Harvard University)
recently made some Cassandra-like statements about oil. Specifically, he said
that this is the worst possible time for an oil price escalation. (In case you
forgot, Cassandra really did have the gift of prophesy, but it was her fate not
to be believed.) Memories are short, and so it might be useful to call attention
to what happened in l982, following the Iranian Revolution: unemployment in the
U.S. reached 10%, employment actually fell for a few months, and some interest
rates came close to 20%. Incidentally, a question that should have been asked is
why didn’t the ‘Fed’ reduce the discount rate? Answer, because despite what
your Economics 101 teacher tried to drum into your head, Central Bank discount
rates hardly matter when really bad news arrives! I seldom make heavy
weather of this unfortunate reality, because if the directors of the Swedish
Central Bank did not have discount-rate posturing and game-playing to occupy
their precious time, they could just as well stay at home, collect some
unemployment compensation, and check out the latest in daytime soap-operas on
the box.
In the Economist (May 29, 2004), there was a long discussion that focussed on
the so-called “spare-capacity crunch”. In l985 OPEC apparently had about 15 mb/d
of spare capacity. Five years later there were down to 5.5 mb/d, and today they
may have only 2 mb/d, with most or even all of the latter located in Saudi
Arabia. This kind of arrangement should make it clear that the price forecasts
of four or five years ago – when the oil price was pictured as falling to $21/b
– were not only inaccurate but foolish. At the same time though the Economist
still peddles the song-and-dance that “the rise of energy futures markets over
the past two decades also offers some scope for the world to deal with
short-term price shocks.”
“Short term” could mean anything, but regardless, the oil futures markets are
some of the best functioning in the world, and I am sure that there are many
transactors who are grateful for the facilities that are available for hedging
price risk. But even so, it needs to be appreciated every minute of every day
that the most efficient and best functioning futures markets (and other
derivatives markets) cannot ameliorate the miseries that could be caused by a
long stretch of tight physical supplies. As far as I am concerned, this can only
be done by imaginative economic policies, designed and implemented by
intelligent governments that accept the seriousness of the present situation and
are capable of thinking in terms of both long and short-term realities
References
Banks, Ferdinand E. (2007). The Political Economy of World Energy:
An Introductory
Textbook. London, New York and Singapore: World Scientific.
Banks, Ferdinand E. (2001). Global Finance and Financial Markets. London,
New York,
and Singapore: World Scientific.
_____ . (2000). Energy Economics: A Modern Introduction. New York: Kluwer
Academ.
Barsky, Robert B. and Lutz Kilian (2004). ‘Oil and the Macroeconomy since the
l970s’.
Journal of Economic Perspectives (Fall).
Bernanke, Ben S. (1983). ‘Irreversibility, Uncertainty, and cyclical investment’.
Quarterly Journal of Economics. (February).
Erdman, Paul (1988). What’s Next? New York: Bantam Books.
Feldstein, Martin (2006). ‘America will fall harder if oil prices rise again’.
Financial
Times (February 3).
Hamilton, James D. (2008). ‘Understanding crude oil prices’. Stencil (revised),
Department of Economics, University of California (San Diego).
Silverstein, Ken (2006). ‘Peak oil: real or not?’. EnergyBiz Insider. (February)
* Uppsala University (Sweden)
Pubblicato su www.AmbienteDiritto.it
l'11/06/2008