AmbienteDiritto.it - Rivista giuridica - Electronic Law Review - Copyright © AmbienteDiritto.it
Testata registrata presso il Tribunale di Patti Reg. n. 197 del 19/07/2006
Nuclear and the New American President
Ferdinand E. Banks*
Abstract
The American election is over,
and just before this event there was a great deal of talk about energy
independence. The Democratic candidate, for example, called for a
“transformation” of the US economy in order to make his country independent of
imported energy – particularly from the Middle East – and this transformation
would feature a recourse to renewables that, supposedly, would enable the
creation of 500,000 new employment opportunities. There might also eventually be
a more widespread tolerance of nuclear energy and the offshore drilling for oil.
In conjunction with my previous publications, and in particular my energy
economics textbooks, I feel that nuclear energy should be recognized as the
natural basis of a new American energy economy. At the same time I can respect
the argument for a large and diverse portfolio of renewables.
Key words: Energy economy, nuclear retreat, capacity factor, toxic waste
Let me start by repeating what I said in an article in the journal Energy and
Environment (2004), We do not know if global warming is the real deal, or just
part of a cycle, but we have discovered that gas and oil can become extremely
expensive in a very short time. In these circumstances the optimal behaviour is
to get friendlier with the friendly atom, and do what former Prime Minister
Blair and the founder of Greenpeace suggest, which is to increase the use of
nuclear energy.
What does nuclear energy have to do with the depletion of oil and gas? As
emphasized in my new energy economics textbook (2007), it has almost everything
to do with it, because nuclear may well be the most flexible of all energy
expedients, in that it can supply the ‘extra energy’ required to e.g. obtain the
large quantities of motor fuels that voters in the energy importing countries
have no intention of doing without, regardless of what they say or believe or
hope. As Len Gould noted in the important forum EnergyPulse
(www.energypulse.net), those voters intend to maintain their transportation
activities at close to the present level – which in many cases is mandatory if
they are to maintain the standard of living of themselves and their families –
even if they must go to war to ensure this outcome.
Germany is a country that, together with Sweden, has expressed a desire to
abandon its nuclear ambitions. After the widespread distribution of my short
paper ‘Some Friendly Economics for the Nuclear Energy Booster Club’, I received
mails from several persons in that country (and elsewhere) requesting their
names to be removed from the list of persons directly receiving my papers. I was
especially surprised by the origin of several of these ‘Dear Johns’, however…
‘Wir Werden Wiedermal Marschieren’ (=We Will March Again), was the title of a
book that gained considerable attention in Germany when I was in that country
with the U.S. Army. It became a best seller, and was about the retaking by the
German military of places like the Sudetenland (in Czechoslovakia) in the coming
Third World War, which the author of that book and many of his readers saw as
inevitable as well as essential for their peace of mind.
Early in my ‘tour’, the armies of Nato countries participated in perhaps the
largest peacetime military manoeuvre ever held in ‘West’ Germany, which was
called ‘Apple Harvest’. Toward the conclusion of that exercise, the referees
ruled that the Red Army had broken through the Fulda Gap and had almost reached
Nuremberg, and it was judged that the only way that they could be stopped was
with nuclear weapons. I had the opportunity to review the calculations for one
of the simulated nuclear projectiles fired from a large cannon at the advancing
Red Army. Had it been real instead of simulated, a portion of the eastern
suburbs of Nuremberg would have been removed from the face of the earth. After
that rather disturbing result came to be known, German officers, journalists,
book-club members, and various decision makers lost their appetite for marching.
The same kind of reversion will likely happen when the German public comes to
realize that abandoning nuclear energy could wreak havoc on their personal
agendas! Among other things it could mean that virtually every factory in
Germany becomes a candidate for transfer to regions with an adequate and
reliable supply of energy.
This is why I make a point of suggesting in my lectures that a more realistic
attitude toward nuclear energy might be wise. The key issue of course is not the
calculations that I make from time to time concerning the economic optimality of
nuclear generating equipment, but my pension! It is also the key issue for many
of academics and energy professionals in this country (Sweden) and probably
elsewhere, although they have been convinced by know-nothing members of the
anti-nuclear booster club and their favourite politicians that they would be
doing themselves a disservice by understanding the easily understandable.
Perhaps the clearest argument for nuclear power has been presented by Rhodes and
Beller (2000), which is similar to the basic contention of this contribution.
They say that “Because diversity and redundancy are important for safety and
security, renewable energy sources ought to retain a place in the energy economy
of the century to come.” The meaning here is clear, especially if you add that
we probably will never possess what is known in intermediate economic theory as
the optimal amount of nuclear power. But they do state that “nuclear power
should be central….Nuclear power is environmentally safe, practical and
affordable. It is not the problem – it is one of the solutions.” Actually, it is
an indispensable component of any rational energy program.
An American President’s Dilemma
During the just concluded presidential campaign in the United States (U.S.),
President-Elect Obama did not express a great deal of confidence in nuclear
energy. Instead he suggested that a larger involvement with renewables should be
undertaken in order to create 500,000 new jobs, and remove the U.S. from the
clutches of foreign sellers of energy. This sounds as if there is some kind of
choice as to what kind of energy structure and strategy should be embraced in
order to restore the economic health of the Republic and ensure its energy
future.
Actually there is no meaningful choice at all if nuclear is excluded or reduced
in scope. As is well known, nuclear energy is not popular with everybody. It
certainly was not a favourite energy preference with many of the young people
who voted for the new president, to include those who came under the influence
of second-rate teachers of energy economics. As for France, mentioned by
Presidential candidate John McCain as an energy roll-model, there are many
persons who hope that someday the 80 percent of the electricity supply that
originates with nuclear can be replaced by another energy source. Frankly, that
yearning seems unrealistic. In countries like France and Japan, where energy
independence is paramount, nuclear energy is not there to be questioned but to
be exploited. ‘No oil, no gas, no coal, no choice’ is the way the French put it,
and although the energy prospects of many other countries may appear rosier at
the present time, they could find themselves in the same predicament some fine
day. The French also prefer the standardize nuclear equipment, which is
something that the US should consider.
Even in Russia, which would be one of the richest countries in the world if its
industrial and agricultural potential were fully developed, plans are being made
to greatly increase its nuclear inventory in order to provide a competitive
advantage with its trading partners, and to develop the Russian economy at a
maximum rate.
This does not mean however that it makes economic or political sense for any
country to ignore conservation and renewables, and/or other non-conventional
energy sources. The ugly fact of the matter is that the world would probably be
in a very bad way if these things do not become prevalent in a few decades, or
perhaps even sooner, because they might have to accommodate a very large part of
the energy burden in all except a few lucky countries. But one way to make sure
that they will not be available is for naive voters and decision-makers to
accept the twisted hypothesis that it is already economical to accelerate the
introduction of these items, in concert with nuclear stagnation or a nuclear
retreat.
Statistical analysis and a simple algebraic demonstration makes it clear that in
terms of reliability and cost, the Swedish nuclear sector was the most efficient
in the world before the curse of (electric) deregulation arrived. It is due to
an intensified concern for the economic future that the irrational nuclear
‘downsizing’ in this country (Sweden) has been at least temporarily halted. The
key departure was upgrading the ten remaining reactors so that they could
produce the same electric energy (in kilowatt-hours = kWh) as the original
twelve reactors, which amounts to nearly 47 percent of the total generated
energy. (Approximately the same amount is accounted for by hydro.) The logic
here is straightforward, and cannot be altered by the resolute ignoring or
downgrading of mainstream economic history: a high electric intensity for
firms, combined with a high rate of industrial investment and the technological
skill created by a modern educational system, will lead to a high productivity
for large and small businesses. This in turn results in a steady increase in
employment, real incomes, and the most important ingredients of social security
(such as pensions and comprehensive health care).
The question for Sweden or the U.S. or anywhere else then becomes whether
welfare aspirations of the kind promised by the new U.S. president can be
realized if the most efficient electric generating facilities in the world are
scrapped or allowed to deteriorate because they did not make the ‘cut’ in a
half-baked popularity contest. For instance, in order to recruit voters with
anti-nuclear tendencies, the former Swedish prime minister informed those
members of the population who prefer opinion and feelings to evidence and logic
that nuclear power was “obsolete”.
Behind this crank conjecture was the allusion that the impressive prosperity of
an industrial country like Sweden could be maintained even if the country’s
nuclear assets were liquidated. What was not mentioned was that few countries
have made as great an effort to include renewables in the energy mainstream as
Sweden, but even so the result in terms of energy generated is insignificant. It
is true that while (technically) renewables can be substituted for nuclear, the
benefit-cost ratio is economically unacceptable. The decision makers in many
other countries know this too, and better today than ever, because as pointed
out in a recent issue of an American news periodical, energy policy has become a
part of security policy.
One more point. I have gotten in the habit of claiming that it is possible to
build a nuclear installation in four years (from ‘ground break’ to grid power).
A gentleman recently pointed out however that I was rendering a disservice to
readers with this contention, stating that in the US there are many factors
which prohibit such a rapid process. Maybe so, but when the price of oil begins
to escalate again, and pundits start talking about an oil price of 200 dollars a
barrel, whatever these factors are they will be brushed aside. How do I know
this? It is because greater political and engineering obstacles were surmounted
during the second World War.
A Technical Consideration
As far as I can tell, wind energy is often pictured as a prominent alternative
to nuclear energy where the generation is of electricity is concerned. In the
United States the billionaire investor T. Boone Pickens has proposed a ‘wind
corridor’ through the middle of the country, from the Rio Grande in the south to
the Canadian border in the north, filled with wind installations generating
electricity that would be inserted into new or old grids and transmitted both
east and west. The aesthetics of this arrangement are not clear to this humble
teacher of economics and finance, but I still remember enjoying the charm of the
occasional windmill as I proceeded by train down the magnificent west coast of
Sweden last summer.
The key term in the above paragraph is “occasional”, because in this country,
where engineering science has always received the highest respect, nobody in
their right mind believes that an all-out commitment to wind energy makes the
slightest engineering or economic or scientific sense, regardless of what they
may say in a disco or student club, or when the television cameras are turned in
their direction. I have a long survey of nuclear energy that I am revising
(2008), however it contains one simple technical aspect of this topic that
everyone should ponder, because it requires only a minimum of secondary school
algebra. It turns on the expression Capacity Factor (CF), which has to do
with the amount of energy that is actually produced over a given period as
compared to the amount that could be produced if the facility had operated at
maximum (or rated) output one-hundred percent of the time. This can be written
CF = Actual Energy Output over a given period divided by Rated or
Maximum Output. When you hear about the beauty of wind energy, make sure
that you ask about the Capacity Factor.
Consider a wind turbine with a power rating of 100 kilowatts. In a month
of 30 days its maximum energy output is 100 x 30 x 24 = 7,200
kilowatt-hours. However its measured output during that period would
likely be lower, and perhaps much lower. Suppose it was 3,600 kilowatt hours.
Then we would have CF = 3600/7200 = 0.50 = 50%. For wind a capacity factor of
15-35% appears average; and the important energy observer and commentator
Jeffrey Michel confirms a stable 0.17 average for Germany before 2007, although
it might have reached 0.2 in 2007. As for nuclear, 30 years ago capacity factors
in the U.S. were about 55% due to the ‘down-time’ caused by unscheduled outages
and scheduled maintenance, but now outages have decreased and average values are
above 85%. Also, if capacity factors are calculated net of scheduled outages,
then from time to time they have reached about 95%. which apparently applies to
plants managed by e.g. Exelon.
By way of extending this theme , we can consider some information about the
capacity factors of wind installations that was presented in EnergyPulse by Len
Gould (2008) and Kenneth Kok (2008). Unfortunately I cannot say whether these
are extreme or typical cases, but they have one thing in common that all readers
of this and other papers on energy economics should observe and remember: the
actual output from wind installations is often not just lower than the rated (or
‘nameplate’) output, but very much lower.
Gould cites an operation by an independent North American wind power company in
which the actual capacity factor for 2007 was somewhere between 8.67% and
17.35%. This might be characterized as a revolution in energy technology in
reverse. Even so, it was superior to a performance noted by Kok, in which a TVA
facility on Buffalo Mountain (near Oliver Springs, Tennessee) registered a
capacity factor considerably under the above figures. In these circumstances it
should be easy to understand why it was impossible to convince the voters and
decision makers in Finland to choose renewables in order to obtain the increase
in electric energy that might be necessary to maintain or augment the standard
of living, despite the considerable dislike of nuclear energy. Put another way,
nuclear installations with very high capacity factors turned out to be
preferable to windmills that did not rotate over very long periods. As I like to
insist, with nuclear energy you generally have an excellent idea of what you are
getting. With e.g. wind (or even solar), you often are unpleasantly surprised.
A Conclusion
“Economics is an easy subject that is difficult”
-John Maynard Keynes
I never tire of mentioning the bizarre fairy tale that was confected by two well
known energy experts, Amory Lovins and Joseph Romm, and published in Foreign
Affairs (1992-93), which is the prestigious journal of the (United States)
Council on Foreign Relations. It goes like this:
“For example, the Swedish State Power Board found that doubling electric
efficiency, switching generators to natural gas and biomass fuels and relying
upon the cleanest power plants would support a 54 per cent increase in real GNP
from l987 to 2010 – while phasing out all nuclear power. Additionally, the heat
and power sector’s carbon dioxide output would fall by one-third, and the costs
of electrical services by nearly $1 billion per year. Sweden is already among
the world’s most energy-efficient countries, even though it is cold, cloudy and
heavily industrialized. Other countries should be able to do better.”
I called that statement completely wrong the first time I saw it, while in my
new textbook (2007) I suggest that it and similar contributions are misleading
bunkum. For example, there are a number of questions that must be answered in
detail before biomass can unambiguously be classified a large- scale
fuel-of-choice for the near future. (See e.g. Grunwald (2008),) As for
renewables such as solar and wind, and probably hydrogen, they will undoubtedly
increase in quality and quantity, but hopefully it will not be at the expense of
nuclear.
On one occasion when I published the above, I was invited to participate in a
telephone conference that featured Dr Lovins. A telephone conference no less.
Better a telephone conference than fisticuffs or a cursing competition next to
the latrine at Camp Gifu (Japan), but fortunately I managed to propose a
suitable alternative. He can put in an appearance in my class in energy
economics the next time I teach at the Asian Institute of Technology (Bangkok),
or for that matter any other institution of higher learning, where he can
attempt to turn into reality some of the dreams of my students in which I am
made a fool of or seriously humiliated.
As David Schlageter pointed out in EnergyPulse (2008), “Renewable energy sources
only supplement the electric grid with intermittent power that rarely matches
the daily electrical demand.” He continues by saying that “In order for an
electric system to remain stable, it needs large generators running 24/7 to
create voltage stability. Wind and solar generation are not on-line when needed
to meet energy demand, and therefore to help decrease system losses.” In the
promised land of wind energy, Denmark, voltage stability is attained by drawing
on the energy resources of Sweden and Germany (and perhaps Norway). The Danes
pay for the imported electricity, but not for the stability – which they would
do in the great world of economic theory. Of course, for the reason suggested
above by Lord Keynes, economic theory does not have much to say about even
crucial energy issues.
It can be suggested though that the Danes may be unable to afford more than
basics where electricity is concerned. According to NUS Consulting (of South
Africa), the price of electricity in Denmark was the highest in the world in
2006 and the next highest in 2005. It can hardly be lower today. In 2005 Sweden
had the next lowest price, and in 2006 the fourth lowest. Something must be
drastically wrong in the Kingdom of Sweden for voters and politicians to remain
passive in the face of this deterioration, particularly when NUS statistics
indicate that the rise in the Swedish price is one of the most rapid in the
world, and is almost certainly due to two things: a preposterous electric
deregulation, and the closing of two nuclear reactors. The thing that should
never be forgotten here is that for geographical and industrial reasons, Sweden
is one of the most energy intensive countries in the world. As a result, a high
energy consumption should be considered by the decision makers a necessity
rather than a luxury, and treated accordingly.
But what about nuclear waste, which is repeatedly portrayed as a malicious and
unavoidable cost of nuclear based electricity because, ostensibly, it will have
to be locked up for hundreds of thousands of years? It is sometimes maintained
however that the cost of disposing of nuclear waste is balanced by the
benefit of no carbon-dioxide (CO2) emissions from reactors. For instance,
the International Energy Agency (IEA) has calculated that for France – the
country with the largest production of nuclear energy (as a fraction of the
total output of electric power) – the average person is responsible for 6.3
tonnes of carbon dioxide (per year), which e.g. is one-third of the U.S. average.
The cost-benefit trade-off mentioned above is worth remembering, however
I prefer for students to know (and be able to explain) why France intends to
treat ‘waste’ as a potential fuel. (A similar strategy has been proposed by the
UK’s energy minister.) A law now exists in France stipulating that toxic waste
is to be stored in such a way that it can be comparatively easily accessed and
recycled if, at some point in the future, “new” technologies appear which will
allow it to be classified a preferable input in the nuclear fuel cycle. This
option was also referred to, indirectly, by presidential candidate John McCain,
however it appears that such thinking is not acceptable to an American audience…yet.
On many occasions I have been told that my own thoughts on nuclear matters are
mistaken because of the subsidies received by the nuclear industries. Everything
is relative in this old world of ours however, and so I continue to insist that
nuclear is essentially subsidy-free. Furthermore, with reference to the second
paragraph in this contribution, I like to cite an observation in the
Financial Times (October 6, 2006). Nuclear power has provided “an abundance
of cheaply-produced electricity, made the country (France) a leader in nuclear
technology worldwide and reduced its vulnerability to the fluctuations of the
turbulent oil and gas markets.”
References
Banks, Ferdinand E. (2008). ‘Economics and nuclear energy: a modern survey’
(Forthcoming).
______ . (2007). The Political Economy of World Energy: An Introductory
Textbook. London, Singapore and New York: World Scientific.
______. (2004). A faith based approached to global warming’. Energy and
Environment. Volume 15, Number 5: 837-852.
Gould, Len (2008). ‘Comment on Banks’. EnergyPulse, (3-26-08).
Grunwald, Michael (2008). ‘The clean energy scam’. Time (April 14).
Kok, Kenneth (2008). ‘Comment on Banks’. EnergyPulse, (3-26-08).
Rhodes, Richard and Denis Beller (2000). ‘The need for nuclear power’. Foreign
Affairs (January-February)
Schlageter, David (2008). ‘Comment on Alan Caruba (‘Congress conjures up an
energy deficit’). www.energypulse.net, Feb 6, 2008.
* Professor of Uppsala University (Sweden).
Pubblicato su www.AmbienteDiritto.it
il 10/11/2008